Web
and Book design,
Copyright, Kellscraft Studio 1999-2015 (Return to Web Text-ures) |
Click
Here to return to
Japan: An Attempt at Interpretation Content Page Return to the Previous Chapter |
(HOME)
|
Modern Restraints It has often been asserted
by foreign observers that the real power in Japan is exercised not from above,
but from below. There is some truth in this assertion, but not all the truth: the
conditions are much too complex to be covered by any general statement. What
cannot be gainsaid is that superior authority has always been more or less
restrained by tendencies to resistance from below.... At no time in Japanese
history, for example, do the peasants appear to have been left without recourse
against excessive oppression, notwithstanding all the humiliating regulations
imposed on their existence. They were suffered to frame their own village-laws,
to estimate the possible amount of their tax payments, and to make protest through
official channels against unmerciful exaction. They were made to pay as much
as they could; but they were not reduced to bankruptcy or starvation; and their
holdings were mostly secured to them by laws forbidding the sale or alienation
of family property. Such was at least the general rule. There were, however,
wicked daimyō, who treated their farmers with extreme cruelty, and found ways
to prevent complaints or protests from reaching the higher authorities. The
almost invariable result of such tyranny was revolt; and the tyrant was then
made responsible for the disorder, and punished. Though denied in theory, the
right of the peasant to rebel against oppression was respected in practice; the
revolt was punished, but the oppressor was likewise punished. Daimyō were
obliged to reckon with their farmers in regard to any fresh imposition of taxes
or forced labour. We also find that although heimin were made subject to the military class, it was possible for
artizans and commercial folk to form, in the great cities, strong associations by
which military tyranny was kept in check. Everywhere the reverential deference
of the common people to authority, as exercised in usual directions, seems to
have been accompanied by an extraordinary readiness to defy authority exercised
in other directions. It may seem strange that a
society in which religion and government, ethics and custom, were practically identical,
should furnish striking examples of resistance to authority. But the religious
fact itself supplies the explanation. From the earliest period there was firmly
established, in the popular mind, the conviction that implicit obedience to
authority was the universal duty under all ordinary circumstances. But with
this conviction there was united another, that resistance to authority
(excepting the sacred authority of the Supreme Ruler) was equally a duty under
extraordinary circumstances. And these seemingly opposed convictions were not really
inconsistent. So long as rule followed precedent, so long as its commands,
however harsh, did not conflict with sentiment and tradition, that rule was
regarded as religious, and there was absolute submission. But when rulers
presumed to break with ethical usage, in a spirit of reckless cruelty or
greed, then the people might feel it a religious obligation to resist with
all the zeal of voluntary martyrdom. The danger-line for every form of local
tyranny was departure from precedent. Even the conduct of regents and princes
was much restrained by the common opinion of their retainers, and by the
knowledge that certain kinds of arbitrary conduct were likely to provoke
assassination. Deference to the sentiment
of vassals and retainers was from ancient time a necessary policy with Japanese
rulers, not merely because of the peril involved by needless oppression, but
much more because of the recognition that duties are well performed only when
subordinates feel assured that their efforts will be fairly considered, and
that sudden needless changes will not be made to their disadvantage. This old policy
still characterizes Japanese administration; and the deference of high
authority to collective opinion astonishes and puzzles the foreign observer. He
perceives only that the conservative power of sentiment, as exercised by groups
of subordinates, remains successfully opposed to those conditions of discipline
which we think indispensable to social progress. Just as in Old Japan the ruler
of a district was held responsible for the behaviour of his subjects, so
to-day, in New Japan, every official in charge of a department is held responsible
for the smooth working of its routine. But this does not mean that he is
responsible only for the efficiency of a service: it means that he is held
responsible likewise for failure to satisfy the wishes of his subordinates, or
at least the majority of his subordinates. If this majority be displeased with
their minister, governor, president, manager, chief, or director, the fact is
considered proof of administrative incompetency.... Perhaps educational circles
afford the most curious examples of this old idea of responsibility. A
student-revolt is commonly supposed to mean, not that the students are
intractable, but that the superintendent or teacher does not know his business.
Thus the principal of a college, the director of a school, holds his office
only on the condition that his rule gives satisfaction to a majority of the
students. In the higher government institutions, each professor or lecturer is
made responsible for the success of his lectures. No matter how great may be
his ability in other directions, the official instructor, unable to make
himself liked by his pupils, will be got rid of in short order unless some
powerful protectors interfere on his behalf. The efforts of the man will never
be judged (officially) by any accepted standard of excellence, never
estimated by their intrinsic worth; they will be considered only according to
their direct effect upon the average of minds.1 Almost everywhere
this antique system of responsibility is maintained. A minister of state is by
public sentiment made responsible not only for the results of his
administration, but likewise for any scandals or troubles that may occur in his
department, independently of the question whether he could or could not have
prevented them. To a considerable degree, therefore, it is true that the ultimate
power is below. The highest official is not able with impunity to impose his
personal will in certain directions; and, for the time being, it is probably
better that his powers are thus restrained. From above downwards
through all the grades of society, the same system of responsibility, and the same
restraints upon individual exercise of will, persist under varying forms. The
conditions within the household differ but little in this regard from the conditions
in a government department: no householder, for example, can impose his will,
beyond certain fixed limits, even upon his own servants or dependents. Neither
for love nor money can a good servant be induced to break with traditional custom;
and the old opinion, that the value of a servant is proved by such
inflexibility, has been justified by the experience of centuries. Popular sentiment
remains conservative; and the apparent zeal for superficial innovation affords
no indication of the real order of existence. Fashions and formalities, house-interiors
and street-vistas, habits and methods, and all the outer aspects of life are
changed; but the old regimentation of society persists under all these
surface-shiftings; and the national character remains little affected by all
the transformations of Meiji. The second kind of coercion
to which the individual is subjected the communal, or communistic seems
likely to prove mischievous in the near future, as it signifies practical suppression
of the right to compete.... The everyday life of any Japanese city offers
numberless suggestions of the manner in which the masses continue to think and
to act by groups. But no more familiar and forcible illustration of the fact
can be cited than that which is furnished by the code of the kurumaya or jinrikisha-men. According to
its terms, one runner must not attempt to pass by another going in the same
direction. Exceptions have been made, grudgingly, in favour of runners in private
employ, men selected for strength and speed, who are expected to use their
physical powers to the utmost. But among the tens of thousands of public kurumaya, it is the rule that a young
and active man must not pass by an old -and feeble man, nor even by a
needlessly slow and lazy man. To take advantage of one's own superior energy,
so as to force competition, is an offence against the calling, and certain to
be resented. You engage a good runner, whom you order to make all speed: he springs
away splendidly, and keeps up the pace until he happens to overtake some weak
or lazy puller, who seems to be moving as slowly as the gait permits.
Therewith, instead of bounding by, your man drops immediately behind the
slow-going vehicle, and slackens his pace almost to a walk. For half an hour,
or more, you may be thus delayed by the regulation which obliges the strong and
swift to wait for the weak and slow. An angry appeal is made to the runner who
dares to pass another; and the idea behind the words might be thus expressed:
"You know that you are breaking the rule, that you are acting to the
disadvantage of your comrades! This is a hard calling; and our lives would be
made harder than they are, if there were no rules to prevent selfish
competition!" Of course there is no thought of the consequences of such
rules to business interests at large.... Now it is not unjust to say that this
moral code of the kurumaya
exemplifies an unwritten law which has been always imposed, in varying forms,
upon every class of workers in Japan: You must not try, without special authorization,
to pass your fellows."... La
carriθre est ouverte aux talents mais la concurrence est defendue! Of course the modern
communal restraint upon free competition represents the survival and extension of
that altruistic spirit which ruled the ancient society, not the mere
continuance of any fixed custom. In feudal times there were no kurumaya; but all craftsmen and all
labourers formed guilds or companies; and the discipline maintained by those guilds
or companies prohibited competition as undertaken for merely personal
advantage. Similar or nearly similar forms of organization are maintained by
artizans and labourers to-day; and the relation of any outside employer to
skilled labour is regulated, by the guild or company, in the old communistic manner....
Let us suppose, for instance, that you wish to have a good house built. For
that undertaking, you will have to deal with a very intelligent class of
skilled labour; for the Japanese house-carpenter may be ranked with the artist
almost as much as with the artizan. You may apply to a building-company; but,
as a general rule, you will do better by applying to a master-carpenter, who combines
in himself the functions of architect, contractor, and builder. In any event
you cannot select and hire workmen: guild-regulations forbid. You can only make
your contract; and the master-carpenter, when his plans have been approved,
will undertake all the rest, purchase and transport of material, hire of
carpenters, plasterers, tilers, mat-makers, screen-fitters, brass-workers,
stone-cutters, locksmiths, and glaziers. For each master-carpenter represents
much more than his own craft-guild: he has his clients in every trade related to
house-building and house-furnishing; and you must not dream of trying to interfere
with his claims and privileges.... He builds your house according to contract;
but that is only the beginning of the relation. You have really made with him
an agreement which you must not break, without good and sufficient reason, for
the rest of your life. Whatever afterwards may happen to any part of your
house, walls, floor, ceiling, roof, foundation, you must arrange for
repairs with him, never with anybody else. Should the roof leak, for instance, you
must not send for the nearest tiler or tinsmith; if the plaster cracks, you
must not send for a plasterer. The man who built your house holds himself
responsible for its condition; and he is jealous of that responsibility: none
but he has the right to send for the plasterer, the roofer, the tinsmith. If
you interfere with that right, you may have some unpleasant surprises. If you
make appeal to the law against that right, you will find that you can get no
carpenter, tiler, or plasterer to work for you at any terms. Compromise is
always possible; but the guilds will resent a needless appeal to the law. And
after all, these craft-guilds are usually faithful performers, and well worth conciliating.
Or take the occupation of
landscape-gardening. You want a pretty garden; and you hire a professional gardener
who comes to you well recommended. He makes the garden; and you pay his price.
But your gardener really represents a company; and by engaging him it is
understood that either he, or some other member of the gardeners' corporation
to which he belongs, will continue to take care of your garden as long as you
own it. At each season he will pay your garden a visit, and put everything to rights:
he will clip the hedges, prune the fruit trees, repair the fences, train the
climbing-plants, look after the flowers, putting up paper awnings to protect
delicate shrubs from the sun during the hot season, or making little tents of
straw to shelter them in time of frost; he will do a hundred useful and
ingenious things for a very small remuneration. You cannot dismiss him,
however, without good reason, and hire another gardener to take his place. No
other gardener would serve you at any price, unless assured that the original
relation had been dissolved by mutual consent. If you have just cause for
complaint, the matter can be settled through arbitration; and the guild will
see that you have no further trouble. But you cannot dismiss your gardener
without cause, merely to engage another. The above examples will
suffice to show the character of the old communistic organization which is yet
maintained in a hundred forms. This communism suppressed competition, except as
between groups; but it insured good work, and secured easy conditions for the
workman. It was the best system possible in those ages of isolation when there
was no such thing as want, and when the population, for yet undetermined
causes, appears to have remained always below the numerical level at which
serious pressure begins.... Another interesting survival is represented by
existing conditions of apprenticeship and service, conditions which also originated
in the patriarchal organization, and imposed other kinds of restraint upon
competition. Under the old regime service was, for the most part, unsalaried.
Boys taken into a commercial house to learn the business, or apprentices bound to
a master-workman, were boarded, lodged, clothed, and even educated by their
patron, with whom they might hope to pass the rest of their lives. But they were
not paid wages until they had learned the business or the trade of their
employer, and were fully capable of managing a business or a workshop of their
own. To a considerable degree these conditions still prevail in commercial
centres, though the merchant or patron seldom now finds it necessary to send
his clerk or apprentice to school. Many of the great commercial houses pay
salaries only to men of great experience: other employιs are only trained and
cared for until their term of service ends, when the most clever among them
will be reengaged as experts, and the others helped to start in business for
themselves. In like manner the apprentice to a trade, when his term expires, may
be reengaged by his master as a hired journeyman, or helped to find permanent
employ elsewhere. These paternal and filial relations between employer and
employed have helped to make life pleasant and labour cheerful; and the quality
of all industrial production must suffer much when they disappear. Even in private domestic
service the patriarchal system still prevails to a degree that is little
imagined; and this subject deserves more than a passing mention. I refer
especially to female service. The maid-servant, according to the old custom, is
not primarily responsible to her employers, but to her own family; and the
terms of her service must be arranged with her family, who pledge themselves for
their daughter's good behaviour. As a general rule, a nice girl does not seek
domestic service for the sake of the wages (which it is now the custom to pay),
nor for the sake of a living, but chiefly to prepare herself for marriage; and
this preparation is desired as much in the hope of doing credit to her own
family, as in the hope of better fitting herself for membership in the family
of her future husband. The best servants are country girls; and they are
sometimes put out to service very young. Parents are careful about choosing the
family into which their daughter thus enters: they particularly desire that the
house be one in which a girl can learn nice ways, therefore a house in which
things are ordered according to the old etiquette. A good girl expects to be
treated rather as a helper than as a hireling, to be kindly considered, and
trusted, and liked. In an old-fashioned household the maid is indeed so treated;
and the relation is not a brief one from three to five years being the term
of service usually agreed upon. But when a girl is taken into service at the
age of eleven or twelve, she will probably remain for eight or ten years. Besides
wages, she is entitled to receive from her employers the gift of a dress, twice
every year, besides other necessary articles of clothing; and she is entitled
also to a certain number of holidays. Such wages, or presents in money, as she
receives, should enable her to provide herself, by degrees, with a good
wardrobe. Except in the event of some extraordinary misfortune, her parents
will make no claim upon her wages; but she remains subject to them; and when
she is called home to be married, she must go. During the period of her
service, the services of her family are also at the disposal of her employers.
Even if the mistress or master desire no recognition of the interest taken in
the girl, some recognition will certainly be made. If the servant be a farmer's
daughter, it is probable that gifts of vegetables, fruits, or fruit trees,
garden-plants or other country products, will be sent to the house at intervals
fixed by custom; if the parents belong to the artizan-class, it is likely
that some creditable example of handicraft will be presented as a token of
gratitude. The gratitude of the parents is not for the wages or the dresses
given to their daughter, but for the practical education she receives, and for
the moral and material care taken of her, as a temporarily adopted child of the
house. The employers may reciprocate such attentions on the part of the parents
by contributing to the girl's wedding outfit. The relation, it will be observed,
is entirely between families, not between individuals; and it is a permanent
relation. Such a relation, in feudal ages, might continue through many
generations. The patriarchal conditions
which these survivals exemplify helped to make existence easy and happy. Only
from a modern point of view is it possible to criticise them. The worst that
can be said about them is that their moral value was chiefly conservative, and
that they tended to repress effort in new directions. But where they still
endure, Japanese life keeps something of its ancient charm; and where they have
disappeared, that charm has vanished forever. There remains to be
considered a third form of restraint, that exercised upon the individual by official
authority. This also presents us with various survivals, which have their
bright as well as their dark aspects. We have seen that the individual
has been legally freed from most of the obligations imposed by the ancient law.
He is no longer obliged to follow a particular occupation; he is able to travel;
he is at liberty to marry into a higher or a lower class than his own; he is
not even forbidden to change his religion; he can do a great many things at
his own risk. But where the law leaves him free, the family and the community
do not; and the persistence of old sentiment and custom nullifies many of the rights
legally conferred. Precisely in the same way, his relations to higher authority
are still controlled by traditions which maintain, in despite of constitutional
law, many of the ancient restraints, and not a little of the ancient coercion.
In theory any man of great talent and energy may rise, from rank to rank, up to
the highest positions. But as private life is still controlled to no small
degree by the old communism, so public life is yet controlled by survivals of
class or clan despotism. The chances for ability to rise without assistance, to
win its way to rank and power, are extraordinarily small; since to contend
alone against an opposition that thinks by groups, and acts by masses, must be
almost hopeless. Only commercial or industrial life now offers really fair
opportunities to capable men. The few talented persons of humble origin who do
succeed in official directions owe their success chiefly to party-help or clan-patronage:
in order to force any recognition of personal ability, group must be opposed to
group, Alone, no man is likely to accomplish anything by mere force of
competition, outside of trade or commerce.... It is true, of course, that
individual talent must in every country encounter many forms of opposition. It
is likewise true that the malevolence of envy and the brutalities of
class-prejudice have their sociological worth: they help to make it impossible
for any but the most gifted to win and to keep success. But in Japan the
peculiar constitution of society lends excessive power to social intrigues
directed against obscure ability, and makes them highly injurious to the
interests of the nation; for at no previous time in her history has Japan needed,
so much as now, the best capacities of her best men, irrespective of class or
condition. But all this was inevitable
in the period of reconstruction. More significant is the fact that in no single
department of its multitudinous service does the Government yet offer
substantial reward to rising merit. No matter how well a man may strive to win
Government approbation, he must strive for little more than honour and the bare
means of existence. The costliest efforts are no more highly paid in proportion
to their worth than the cheapest; the most invaluable services are scarcely
better recognized than those most easily dispensed with or replaced. (There
have been some remarkable exceptions: I am stating only the general rule.) By
extraordinary energy, patience, and cleverness, one may reach, with class-help,
some position which in Europe would assure comfort as well as honour; but the
emoluments of such a position in Japan will scarcely cover the actual cost of
living. Whether in the army or in the navy, in the departments of justice, of
education, of communications, or of home affairs, the differences in
remuneration nowhere represent the differences in capacity and responsibility.
To rise from grade to grade signifies pecuniarily almost nothing, for the
expenses of each higher position augment out of all proportion to the salaries
fixed by law. The general rule has been to exact everywhere the greatest
possible amount of service for the least possible amount of pay.2
Any one unacquainted with the social history of the country might suppose that
the policy of the Government toward its employιs consisted in substituting
empty honours for material advantages. But the truth is that the Government has
simply maintained, under modern forms, the ancient feudal condition of service,
service in exchange for the means of simple but honourable living. In feudal
times the farmer was expected to pay all that he could pay for the right to
exist; the artist or artizan was expected to content himself with the good
fortune of having a distinguished patron; even the ordinary samurai were
supplied with barely more than the necessary by their liege-lords. To receive
considerably more than the necessary signified extraordinary favour; and the
gift was usually accompanied by promotion. But although the same policy is yet
successfully maintained by Government, under the modem system of money-payments,
the conditions everywhere, outside of commercial life, are incomparably harder
than in feudal times. Then the poorest samurai was secured against want, and not
liable to be dismissed from his post without fault. Then the teacher received
no salary; but the respect of the community and the gratitude of his pupils
assured him of the means to live respectably. Then the artizans were patronized
by great lords who vied with each other in the encouragement of humble genius.
They might expect the genius to be satisfied with merely nominal payment, so
far as money was concerned; but they secured him against want or discomfort,
allowed him ample leisure to perfect his work, made him happy in the certainty
that his best would be prized and praised. But now that the cost of living has
tripled or quadrupled, even the artist and the artizan have small encouragement
to do their best: cheap rapid work is replacing the beautiful leisurely work of
the old days; and the best traditions of the crafts are doomed to perish. It
cannot even be said that the state of the agricultural classes to-day is
happier or better than in the time when a farmer's land could not legally be
taken from him. And as the cost of life continues always to increase, it is
evident that at no distant time, the present patient order of things will become
impossible. To many it would seem that
a wise government must recognize the impracticability of indefinitely maintaining
its present demand for self-sacrifice, must perceive the necessity of
encouraging talent, inviting fair competition, and making the prizes of life
large enough to stimulate healthy egoism. But it is possible that the
Government has been acting more wisely than outward appearances would indicate.
Several years ago a Japanese official made in my presence this curious
observation: Our Government does not wish to encourage competition beyond the
necessary. The people are not prepared for it; and if it were strongly
encouraged, the worst side of character would come to the surface. How far
this statement really expressed any policy I do not know. But every one is
aware that free competition can be made as cruel and as pitiless as war, though
we are apt to forget what experience must have been undergone before Occidental
free competition could become as comparatively merciful as it is. Among a
people trained for centuries to regard all selfish competition as criminal, and
all profit-seeking despicable, any sudden stimulation of effort for purely
personal advantage might well be impolitic. Evidence as to how little the
nation was prepared, twelve or thirteen years ago, for Western forms of free
government, has been furnished by the history of the earlier district-elections
and of the first parliamentary sessions. There was really no personal enmity in
those furious election-contests, which cost so many lives; there was scarcely
any personal antagonism in those parliamentary debates of which the violence
astonished strangers. The political struggles were not really between individuals,
but between clan-interests, or party-interests; and the devoted followers of
each clan or party understood the new politics only as a new kind of war, a
war of loyalty to be fought for the leader's sake, a war not to be interfered
with by any abstract notions of right or justice. Suppose that a people have
been always accustomed to think of loyalty in relation to persons rather than
to principles, loyalty as involving the duty of self-sacrifice regardless of
consequence, it is obvious that the first experiments of such a people with
parliamentary government will not reveal any comprehension of fair play in the
Western sense. Eventually that comprehension may come; but it will not come
quickly. And if you can persuade such a people that in other matters every man
has a right to act according to his own convictions, and for his own advantage,
independently of any group to which he may belong, the immediate result will
not be fortunate, because the sense of individual moral responsibility has
not yet been sufficiently cultivated outside of the group-relation. The probable truth is that
the strength of the government up to the present time has been chiefly due to
the conservation of ancient methods, and to the survival of the ancient spirit
of reverential submission. Later on, no doubt, great changes will have to be
made; meanwhile, much must be bravely endured. Perhaps the future history of
modern civilization will hold record of nothing more touching than the patient
heroism of those myriads of Japanese patriots, content to accept, under legal conditions
of freedom,, the official servitude of feudal days, satisfied to give their
talent., their strength, their utmost effort, their lives, for the simple
privilege of obeying a government that still accepts all sacrifices in the
feudal spirit as a matter of course, as a national duty. And as a national
duty, indeed, the sacrifices are made. All know that Japan is in danger,
between the terrible friendship of England and the terrible enmity of Russia,
that she is poor, that the cost of maintaining her armaments is straining her
resources, that it is everybody's duty to be content with as little as
possible. So the complaints are not many.... Nor has the simple obedience of
the nation at large been less touching, especially, perhaps, as regards the
imperial order to acquire Western knowledge, to learn Western languages, to
imitate Western ways. Only those who have lived in Japan during or before the early
nineties are qualified to speak of the loyal eagerness that made
self-destruction by over-study a common form of death, the passionate
obedience that impelled even children to ruin their health in the effort to
master tasks too difficult for their little minds (tasks devised by
well-meaning advisers with no knowledge of Far-Eastern psychology), and the
strange courage of persistence in periods of earthquake and conflagration, when
boys and girls used the tiles of their ruined homes for school-slates, and bits
of fallen plaster for pencils. What tragedies I might relate even of the higher
educational life of universities! of fine brains giving way under pressure of
work beyond the capacity of the average European student, of triumphs won in the
teeth of death, of strange farewells from pupils in the time of the dreaded
examinations, as when one said to me: "Sir, I am very much afraid that my
paper is bad, because I came out of the hospital to make it there is
something the matter with my heart." (His diploma was placed in his hands
scarcely an hour before he died.)... And all this striving striving not only
against difficulties of study, but in most cases against difficulties of
poverty, and underfeeding, and discomfort has been only for duty, and the
means to live. To estimate the Japanese student by his errors, his failures, his
incapacity to comprehend sentiments and ideas alien to the experience of his
race, is the mistake of the shallow: to judge him rightly one must have learned
to know the silent moral heroism of which he is capable. 1 Unjust as this policy must appear to the Western reader (a policy which
certainly presupposes ethical conditions very different from our own), it was
probably at one time the best possible under the new order. Considering the extraordinary
changes suddenly made in the educational system, it will be obvious that a
teacher's immediate value was likely twenty years ago to depend on his
ability to make his teaching attractive. If he attempted to teach either above
or below the average capacity of his pupils, or if he made his instruction
unpalatable to minds greedy for new knowledge, but innocent as to method, his
inexperience could be corrected by the will of his class. 2 Salaries of judges range from £70 to £500 per annum, the latter
figure representing the highest possible emolument. The highest salary allowed
to a Japanese professor in the imperial universities has been fixed at £120.
The wages of employιs in the postal departments is barely sufficient to meet
the cost of living. The police are paid from £1 to £1 10s. per month, according
to locality} and the average pay of school-teachers is yet lower (being 9 yen 50 sen, or about 19s. per
month), many receiving less than 7s.
a month. Readers may be interested
in the following table of army-payments (1904): When these rates of pay were fixed, about twenty years ago, house-rent was cheap: a good house could be rented anywhere at 3 yen or 4 yen per month. To-day in Tōkyō an officer can scarcely rent even a very small house at less than 18 yen or 20 yen; and prices of food-stuffs have tripled. Yet there have been very few complaints. Officers whose pay will not allow them to rent houses hire rooms wherever they can. Many suffer hardship; but all are proud of the privilege of serving, and no one dreams of resigning. |